Capital Vol. III Part V
Division of Profit into Interest and Profit of Enterprise
Interest-Bearing Capital
Chapter 25. Credit and Fictitious Capital
An exhaustive an*lysis of the credit system and of the instruments which it creates for its own use (credit-money, etc.) lies beyond our plan. We merely wish to dwell here upon a few particular points, which are required to characterise the capitalist mode of production in general. We shall deal only with commercial and bank credit. The connection between the development of this form of credit and that of public credit will not be considered here.
I have shown earlier (Buch I, Kap. III, 3, b [English edition: Ch. III, 3, b. — Ed.]) how the function of money as a means of payment, and therewith a relation of creditor and debtor between the producer and trader of commodities, develop from the simple circulation of commodities. With the development of commerce and of the capitalist mode of production, which produces solely with an eye to circulation, this natural basis of the credit system is extended, generalised, and worked out. Money serves here, by and large, merely as a means of payment, i.e., commodities are not sold for money, but for a written promise to pay for them at a certain date. For brevity's sake, we may put all these promissory notes under the general head of bills of exchange. Such bills of exchange, in their turn, circulate as means of payment until the day on which they fall due; and they form the actual commercial money. Inasmuch as they ultimately neutralise one another through the balancing of claims and debts, they act absolutely as money, although there is no eventual transformation into actual money. Just as these mutual advances of producers and merchants make up the real foundation of credit, so does the instrument of their circulation, the bill of exchange, form the basis of credit-money proper, of bank-notes, etc. These do not rest upon the circulation of money, be it metallic or government-issued paper money, but rather upon the circulation of bills of exchange.
W. Leatham (banker of Yorkshire) writes in his Letters on the Currency, 2nd ed., London, 1840:
"I find, then, the amount for the whole of the year of 1839...
to be £528,493,842" (he a**umed that the foreign bills of
exchange made up about one-fifth of the total) "and the
amount of bills out at one time in the above year, to be
£132,123,460" (p. 56). The bills of exchange make up
"one component part greater in amount than all the
rest put together" (p. 3). "This enormous superstructure
of bills of exchange rests (!) upon the base formed by
the amount of bank-notes and gold, and when, by events,
this base becomes too much narrowed, its solidity
and very existence is endangered" (p. 8). "If I estimate
the whole currency"
(he means of the bank-notes)
"and the amount of the liabilities of the Bank
and country bankers, payable on demand, I find a sum of
153 million, which, by law, can be converted into gold ...
and the amount of gold to meet this demand" only 14
million (p.11). "The bills of exchange are not ...
placed under any control, except by preventing the abundance
of money, excessive and low rates of interest or discount,
which create a part of them, and encourage their great and
dangerous expansion. It is impossible to decide what
part arises out of real bonâ fide transactions,
such as actual bargain and sale, or what part is fictitious
and mere accommodation paper, that is, where one bill of
exchange is drawn to take up another running, in order
to raise a fictitious capital, by creating so much currency.
In times of abundance and cheap money this I know reaches
an enormous amount"
(pp. 43-44). J.W. Bosanquet, Metallic, Paper and Credit Currency, London, 1842:
"An average amount of payments to the extent of upwards of
£3,000,000 is settled through the Clearing House
(where the London bankers exchange due bills and filed cheques)
every day of business in the year, and the daily amount
of money required for the purpose is little more than £200,000"
(p. 86).
(In 1889, the total turnover of the Clearing House amounted to £7,618.75 million, which, in roughly 300 business days, averages £25½ million daily. — F. E.]
"Bills of exchange act undoubtedly as currency,
independent of money, inasmuch as they transfer property from
hand to hand by endorsement" (p. 92). "It may be a**umed
that upon an average there are two endorsements upon every
bill in circulation, and ... each bill performs two payments
before it becomes due. Upon this a**umption it would appear,
that by endorsement alone property changed hands, by means of
bills of exchange, to the value of twice five hundred and
twenty-eight million, or £1,056,000,000, being at
the rate of more than £3,000,000 per day, in the course of
the year 1839. We may safely therefore conclude, that
deposits and bills of exchange together, perform the
functions of money, by transferring property from
hand and to hand without the aid of money, to an extent daily
of not less than £18,000,000" (p. 93).
Tooke says the following about credit in general:
"Credit, in its most simple expression, is the confidence
which, well, or ill-founded, leads a person to entrust another
with a certain amount of capital, in money, or in goods computed
at a value in money agreed upon, and in each case payable at
the expiration of a fixed term. In the case where the capital is
lent in money, that is whether in bank-notes, or in a cash
credit, or in an order upon a correspondent, an addition
for the use of the capital of so much upon every £100 is made
to the amount to be repaid. In the case of goods the value of
which is agreed in terms of money, constituting a sale, the
sum stipulated to be repaid includes a consideration
for the use of the capital and for the risk, till the
expiration of the period fixed for payment. Written obligations
of payment at fixed dates mostly accompany these credits,
and the obligations or promissory notes after date being
transferable, form the means by which the lenders, if they
have occasion for the use of their capital, in the shape whether
of money or goods, before the expiration of the term of
the bills they hold, are mostly enabled to borrow Or to
buy on lower terms, by having their own credit strengthened
by the names on the bills in addition to their own."
(Inquiry into the Currency Principle, p. 87.)
Ch. Coquelin, Du Crédit et des Banques dans L'Industrie, Revue des Deux Mondes, 1842, Tome 31:
"In every country the majority of credit transactions takes
place within the circle of industrial relations...
The producer of the raw material advances it to the
processing manufacturer, and receives from the latter
a promise to pay on a certain day. The manufacturer, having
completed his share of the work, in his turn advances his
product on similar terms to another manufacturer,
who has to process it further, and in this way credit
stretches on and on, from one to the other, right up to
the consumer. The wholesale dealer gives the retailer
commodities on credit, while receiving credit from a
manufacturer or commission agent. All borrow with one hand
and lend with the other, sometimes money, but more frequently
products. In this manner an incessant exchange of
advances, which combine and intersect in all directions,
takes place in industrial relations. The development
of credit consists precisely in this multiplication and
growth of mutual advances, and therein is the real seat
of its power."
The other side of the credit system is connected with the development of money-dealing, which, of course, keeps step under capitalist production with the development of dealing in commodity. We have seen in the preceding part (Chap. XIX) how the care of the reserve funds of businessmen, the technical operations of receiving and disbursing money, of international payments, and thus of the bullion trade, are concentrated in the hands of the money-dealers. The other side of the credit system — the management of interest-bearing capital, or money-capital, develops alongside this money-dealing as a special function of the money-dealers. Borrowing and lending money becomes their particular business. They act as middlemen between the actual lender and the borrower of money-capital. Generally speaking, this aspect of the banking business consists of concentrating large amounts of the loanable money-capital in the bankers' hands, so that, in place of the individual money-lender, the bankers confront the industrial capitalists and commercial capitalists as representatives of all moneylenders. They become the general managers of money-capital. On the other hand by borrowing for the entire world of commerce, they concentrate all the borrowers vis-à-vis all the lenders. A bank represents a centralisation of money-capital, of the lenders, on the one hand, and on the other a centralisation of the borrowers. Its profit is generally made by borrowing at a lower rate of interest than it receives in loaning.
The loanable capital which the banks have at their disposal streams to them in various ways. In the first place, being the cashiers of the industrial capitalists, all the money-capital which every producer and merchant must have as a reserve fund, or receives in payment, is concentrated in their hands. These funds are thus converted into loanable money-capital. In this way, the reserve fund of the commercial world, because it is concentrated in a common treasury, is reduced to its necessary minimum, and a portion of the money-capital which would otherwise have to lie slumbering as a reserve fund, is loaned out and serves as interest-bearing capital. In the second place, the loanable capital of the banks is formed by the deposits of money-capitalists who entrust them with the business of loaning them out. Furthermore, with the development of the banking system, and particularly as soon as banks came to pay interest on deposits, money savings and the temporarily idle money of all cla**es were deposited with them. Small amounts, each in itself incapable of acting in the capacity of money-capital, merge together into large ma**es and thus form a money power. This aggregation of small amounts must be distinguished as a specific function of the banking system from its go-between activities between the money-capitalists proper and the borrowers. In the final an*lysis, the revenues, which are usually but gradually consumed, are also deposited with the banks.
The loan is made (we refer here strictly to commercial credit) by discounting bills of exchange — by converting bills of exchange into money before they come due — and by advances of various kinds: direct advances on personal credit, loans against securities, such as interest-bearing paper, government paper, stocks of all sorts, and, notably, overdrafts against bills of lading, dock warrants, and other certified titles of ownership of commodities and overdrawing deposits, etc.
The credit given by a banker may a**ume various forms, such as bills of exchange on other banks, cheques on them, credit accounts of the same kind, and finally, if the bank is entitled to issue notes — bank-notes of the bank itself. A bank-note is nothing but a draft upon a banker, payable at any time to the bearer, and given by the banker in place of private drafts. This last form of credit appears particularly important and striking to the layman, first, because this form of credit-money breaks out of the confines of mere commercial circulation into general circulation, and serves there as money; and because in most countries the principal banks issuing notes, being a peculiar mixture of national and private banks, actually have the national credit to back them, and their notes are more or less legal tender; because it is apparent here that the banker deals in credit itself, a bank-note being merely a circulating token of credit. But the banker also has to do with credit in all its other forms, even when he advances the cash money deposited with him. In fact, a bank-note simply represents the coin of wholesale trade, and it is always the deposit which carries the most weight with banks. The best proof of this is furnished by the Scottish banks.
Special credit institutions, like special forms of banks, need no further consideration for our purpose.
"The business of bankers ... may be divided into two
branches... One branch of the banker's business is
to collect capital from those who have not
immediate employment for it, and to distribute or transfer
it to those who have. The other branch is to receive
deposits of the incomes of their customers, and to pay
out the amount, as it is wanted for expenditure by the
latter in the objects of their consumption... The former
being a circulation of capital, the latter of currency... "
— "One relates to the concentration of capital
on the one hand and the distribution of it on the
other, the other is employed in administering the circulation
for local purposes of the district." Tooke, Inquiry
into the Currency Principle, pp. 36, 37.
We shall revert to this pa**age later, in Chapter XXVIII.
Reports of Committees, Vol. VIII. Commercial Distress, Vol. 11, Part I, 1847-48, Minutes of Evidence. (Further quoted as Commercial Distress, 1847-48.) In the forties, when discounting bills of exchange in London, 21-day drafts of one bank on another were often accepted in lieu of banknotes. (Testimony of J. Pease, country banker, Nos. 4638 and 4645.) According to the same report, bankers were in the habit of giving such bills of exchange regularly in payment to their customers whenever money was tight. If the receiver wanted bank-notes, he had to rediscount this bill. For the banks this amounted to a privilege of coining money. Messrs. Jones, Lloyd and Co. made payments in this way "from time immemorial," as soon as money was scarce and the rate of interest rose above 5%. The customer was glad to get such banker's bills because bills from Jones, Loyd and Co. were easier discounted than his own; besides, they often pa**ed through twenty to thirty hands. (Ibid., Nos. 901 to 904, 905, 992.)
All these forms serve to make the payments claim transferable.
"There is scarcely any shape into which credit can be cast,
in which it will not at times be called to perform the
functions of money; and whether that shape be a bank-note,
or a bill of exchange, or a banker's cheque, the process
is in every essential particular the same, and the result
is the same." Fullarton, On the Regulation of Currencies,
2nd ed., London, 1845, p. 38. — "Bank-notes are the small
change of credit" (p. 51).
The following from J. W. Gilbart's The History and Principle of Banking, London, 1834:
"The trading capital of a bank may be divided into two
parts: the invested capital, and the borrowed banking
capital" (p. 117). "There are three ways of raising a
banking or borrowed capital. First, by receiving;
secondly, by the issuing of notes; thirdly, by the drawing
of bills. If a person will lend me £100 for nothing, and I
lend that £100 to another person at four per cent interest,
then, in the course of a year, I shall gain £4 by the
transaction. Again, if a person will take my 'promise to
pay'" ("I promise to pay" is the usual formula for English
bank-notes) "and bring it back to me at the end of the year,
and pay me four per cent for it, just the same as though I
had lent him 100 sovereigns, then I shall gain £4 by that
transaction; and again, if a person in a country town
brings me £100 on condition that, twenty-one days afterwards,
I shall pay the same amount to a person in London, then
whatever interest I can make of the money during the
twenty-one days, will be my profit. This is a fair
representation of the operations of banking, and of the
way in which a banking capital is created by means of
deposits, notes, and bills" (p. 117). "The profits of a
banker are generally in proportion to the amount of his
banking or borrowed capital... To ascertain the real profit
of a bank, the interest upon the invested capital should
be deducted from the gross profit, and what remains is the
banking profit" (p. 118). "The advances of bankers to
their customers are made with other people's money"
(p. 146). "Precisely those bankers who do not issue notes,
create a banking capital by the discounting of bills.
They render their discounts subservient to the increase
of their deposits. The London bankers will not discount
except for those houses who have deposit accounts with them"
(p. 119). "A party who has had bills discounted, and has
paid interest on the whole amount, must leave some portion of
that amount in the hands of the banker without interest.
By this means the banker obtains more than the current rate
of interest on the money actually advanced, and raises a
banking capital to the amount of the balance left in his
hands" (pp. 119- 20).
Economising on reserve funds, deposits, cheques:
"Banks of deposit serve to economise the use of the
circulating medium. This is done upon the principle of
transfer of titles.... Thus it is that banks of deposit ...
are enabled to settle a large amount of transactions
with a small amount of money. The money thus liberated,
is employed by the banker in making advances, by discount
or otherwise, to his customers. Hence the principle of
gives additional efficiency to the deposit system..." (p. 123). "
It matters not whether the two parties, who have
dealings with each other, keep their accounts with the
same banker or with different bankers; for, as the
bankers exchange their cheques with each other at the
clearing house.... The deposit system might thus, by
means of transfers, be carried to such an extent as wholly
to supersede the use of a metallic currency. Were every man
to keep a deposit account at a bank, and make all his
payments by cheques, money might be superseded, and cheques
become the sole circulating medium. In this case,
however, it must be supposed that the banker has the money
in his hands, or the cheques would have no value" (p. 124).
Centralisation of local transactions in the hands of the banks is effected 1) through branch banks. Country banks have branch establishments in the smaller towns of their district, and London banks in different districts of the city. 2) Through agencies.
"Each country banker employs a London agent to pay his
notes or bills ... and to receive sums that may be lodged
by parties residing in London for the use of parties residing
in the country" (p.127). "Each banker accepts the notes
of others, but does not reissue them. In all larger cities
they come together once or twice a week and exchange their
notes. The balance is paid by a draft on London" (p.134).
"It is the object of banking to give facilities to trade,
and whatever gives facilities to trade gives facilities to
speculation. Trade and speculation are in some cases so
nearly allied, that it is impossible to say at
what precise point trade ends and speculation begins....
Wherever there are banks, capital is more readily obtained,
and at a cheaper rate. The cheapness of capital gives
facilities to speculation, just in the same way as the
cheapness of beef and of beer gives facilities to
gluttony and drunkenness" (pp. 137, 438). "As banks of
circulation always issue their own notes, it would seem that
their discounting business was carried on exclusively
with this last description of capital, but it is not so.
It is very possible for a banker to issue his own notes for
all the bills he discounts, and yet nine-tenths of the
bills in his possession shall represent real capital.
For, although in the first instance, the banker's
notes are given for the bill, yet these notes may not stay in
circulation until the bill becomes due — the bill may have
three months to run, the notes may return in three days" (p. 172).
"The overdrawing of a cash credit account is a regular matter
of business; it is, in fact, the purpose for which the
cash credit has been granted.... Cash credits are granted
not only upon personal security, but also upon the security
of the Public Funds" (pp. 174, 175). "Capital advanced,
by way of loan, on the securities of merchandise, would
produce the same effects as if advanced in the discounting
of bills. If a party borrows 1400 on the security of his
merchandise, it is the same as though he had sold his
merchandise for a 8100 bill, and got it discounted with the
banker. By obtaining this advance he is enabled to hold
over this merchandise for a better market, and avoids a
sacrifice which, otherwise, be might be induced to make,
order to raise the money for urgent purposes" (pp. 180-81).
The Currency Theory Reviewed, etc., pp. 62-63:
"It is unquestionably true that the £1,000 which you deposit
at A today may be reissued tomorrow, and form a
deposit at B. The day after that, reissued from B, it may
form a deposit at C ... and so on to infinitude; and that
the same £1,000 in money may thus, by a succession of transfers,
multiply itself into a sum of deposits absolutely
indefinite. It is possible, therefore, that nine-
tenths of all the deposits in the United Kingdom may have
no existence beyond their record in the books of the
bankers who are respectively accountable for them ...
Thus in Scotland, for instance, currency (mostly paper
money at that) has never exceeded £3 million, the deposits
in the banks are estimated at £27 million.... Unless a run
on the banks be made, the same £1,000 would, if sent
back upon its travels, cancel with the same facility a sum
equally indefinite. As the same £1,000 with which you
cancel your debt to a tradesman today, may cancel his debt
the merchant tomorrow, the merchant's debt to the
bank the day following, and so on without end; so the same
£1,000 may pa** from hand to hand, and bank to bank, and
cancel any conceivable sum of deposits."
[We have seen that Gilbart knew even in 1834 that
"whatever gives facilities to trade gives facilities to
speculation. Trade and speculation are in some cases so
nearly allied, that it is impossible to say at what
precise point trade ends and speculation begins."
The easier it is to obtain advances on unsold commodities, the more such advances are taken, and the greater the temptation to manufacture commodities, or dump already manufactured commodities in distant markets, just to obtain advances of money on them. To what extent the entire business world of a country may be seized by such swindling, and what it finally comes to, is amply illustrated by the history of English business during 1845-47. It shows us what credit can accomplish. Before pa**ing on to the following examples, a few preliminary remarks.
At the close of 1842 the pressure which English industry suffered almost uninterruptedly since 1837, began to lift. During the following two years foreign demand for English manufactured goods increased still more; 1845 and 1846 marked a period of greatest prosperity. In 1843 the Opium War had opened China to English commerce. The new market gave a new impetus to the further expansion of an expanding industry, particularly the cotton industry. "How can we ever produce too much? We have to clothe 300 million people," a Manchester manufacturer said to this writer at the time. But all the newly erected factory buildings, steam-engines, and spinning and weaving machines did not suffice to absorb the surplus-value pouring in from Lancashire. With the same zeal as was shown in expanding production, people engaged in building railways. The thirst for speculation of manufacturers and merchants at first found gratification in this field, and as early as in the summer of 1844. Stock was fully underwritten, i.e., so far as there was money to cover the initial payments. As for the rest, time would show! But when further payments were due — Question 1059, C. D. 1848/57, indicates that the capital invested in railways in 1846-47 amounted to £75 million — recourse had to be taken to credit, and in most cases the basic enterprises of the firm had also to bleed.
And in most cases these basic enterprises were already over-burdened. The enticingly high profits had led to far more extensive operations than justified by the available liquid resources. Yet there was credit-easy to obtain and cheap. The bank discount rate stood low: 1¾ to 2¾% in 1844, less than 3% until October 1845, rising to 5% for a while (February 1846), then dropping again to 3¼% in December 1846. The Bank of England had an unheard-of supply of gold in its vaults. All inland quotations were higher than ever before. Why then allow this splendid opportunity to escape? Why not go in for all one was worth? Why not send all one could manufacture to foreign markets which pined for English goods? And why should not the manufacturer himself pocket the double gain arising from selling yarn and fabrics in the Far East, and the return cargo in England?
Thus arose the system of ma** consignments to India and China against advance payments, and this soon developed into a system of consignments purely for the sake of getting advances, as described in greater detail in the following notes, which led inevitably to over-flooding the markets and a crash.
The crash was precipitated by the crop failure of 1846. England, and particularly Ireland, required enormous imports of foodstuffs, notably corn and potatoes. But the countries which supplied them could be paid with the products of English industry only to a very limited extent. Precious metals had to be given out. Gold worth at least nine million was sent abroad. Of this amount no less than seven and a half million came from the treasury of the Bank of England, whose freedom of action on the money-market was thereby considerably impaired. Other banks, whose reserves were deposited with the Bank of England and were practically identical with those of that Bank, were thus also compelled to curtail accommodation of money. The rapid and easy flow of payments was obstructed, first here and there, then generally. The banking discount rate, still 3 to 3½% in January 1847, rose to 7% in April, when the first panic broke out. The situation eased somewhat in the summer (6½%, 6%), but when the new crop failed as well panic broke out afresh and even more violently. The official minimum bank discount rose in October to 7 and in November to 10%; i.e., the overwhelming ma** of bills of exchange was discountable only at outrageous rates of interest, or no longer discountable at all. The general cessation of payments caused the failure of several leading and very many medium-sized and small firms. The Bank itself was in danger due to the limitations imposed by the artful Bank Act of 1844. The government yielded to the general clamour and suspended the Bank Act on October 25, thereby eliminating the absurd legal fetters imposed on the Bank. Now it could throw its supply of bank-notes into circulation without hindrance. The credit of these bank-notes being in practice guaranteed by the credit of the nation, and thus unimpaired, the money stringency was thus instantly and decisively relieved. Naturally, quite a number of hopelessly enmeshed large and small firms failed nevertheless, but the peak of the crisis was overcome, the banking discount dropped to 5% in December, and in the course of 1848 a new wave of business activity began which took the edge off the revolutionary movements on the continent in 1849, and which inaugurated in the fifties an unprecedented industrial prosperity, but then ended again — in the crash of 1857. — F. E.]
I. A document issued by the House of Lords in 1848 deals with the colossal depreciation of government paper and bonds during the 1847 crisis. According to it the depreciation of October 23, 1847, compared with the level in February of the same year, amounted to:
On English government bonds £93,824,217
On dock and can*l stock £1,358,288
On railway stock £19,579,820
Total £114,762,325
II. With reference to the swindle in East Indian trade, in which drafts were no longer drawn because commodities were being bought, but rather commodities were bought to be able to make out discountable drafts convertible into money, the Manchester Guardian of November 24, 1847, remarks:
Mr. A in London instructs a Mr. B to buy from the manufacturer C in Manchester commodities for shipment to a Mr. D in East India. B pays C in six months' drafts to be made out by C on B. B secures himself by six months' drafts on A. As soon as the goods are shipped A makes out six months' drafts on D against the mailed bill of lading.
"The shipper and the co-signee were thus both put in
possession of funds — months before they actually paid
for the goods; and, very commonly, these bills were renewed
at maturity, on pretence of affording time for the
returns in a 'long trade'. Unfortunately, losses by
such a trade, instead of leading to its contraction, led
directly to its increase. The poorer men became, the
greater need they had to purchase, in order to make up, by
new advances, the capital they had lost on the past adventures.
Purchases thus became, not a question of supply and
demand, but the most important part of the finance
operations of a firm labouring under difficulties. But
this is only one side of the picture. What took place
in reference to the export of goods at home, was taking
place in the purchase and shipment of produce abroad. Houses
in India, who had credit to pa** their bills, were purchasers
of sugar, indigo, silk, or cotton — not because the prices
advised from London by the last overland mail promised a
profit on the prices current in India, but because former
drafts upon the London house would soon fall due, and must be
provided for. What was so simple as to purchase a cargo of
sugar, pay for it in bills upon the London house at ten
months' date, transmit the shipping documents by
the overland mail; and, in less than two months, the goods
on the high seas, or perhaps not yet pa**ed the mouth of
the Hoogly, were pawned in Lombard Street — putting the
house in funds eight months before the drafts against those
goods fell due. And all this went on without interruption or
difficulty, as long as bill-brokers had abundance of
money 'at call,'; to advance on bills of lading and dock
warrants, and to discount, without limit, the bills of India
houses drawn upon the eminent firms in Mincing Lane."
[This fraudulent procedure remained in vogue so long as goods to and from India had to round the Cape in sailing vessels. But ever since they are being shipped in steamboats via the Suez Can*l this method of fabricating fictitious capital has been deprived of its basis — the long freight voyage. And ever since the telegraph informs the English businessman about the Indian market and the Indian merchant about the English market, on the same day this method has become totally impracticable. — F.E.]
III. The following is taken from the quoted Report on Commercial Distress, 1847-48:
"In the last week of April 1847, the Bank of England advised
the Royal Bank of Liverpool that it would thereafter reduce
its discount business with the latter bank by one-half.
The announcement operated with peculiar hardship
with peculiar hardship on this account, that the payments
into Liverpool had latterly been much more in bills than
in cash; and the merchants who generally brought to
the Bank a large proportion of cash with which to pay
their acceptances, had latterly been able to bring only
bills which they had received for their cotton and other
produce, and that Increased very rapidly as the difficulties
increased.... The acceptances ... which the Bank had to
pay for the merchants, were acceptances drawn chiefly
upon them from abroad, and they have been accustomed to
meet those acceptances by whatever payment they received for
their produce.... The bills that the merchants brought...
in lieu of cash, which they usually brought ... were
of various dates, and of various descriptions; a considerable
number of them were bankers' bills, of three months'
date, the large bulk being cotton bills. These bills of
exchange, when bankers' bills, were accepted by London
bankers, and by merchants in every trade that we could mention
— the Brazilian, the American, the Canadian, the West Indian....
The merchants did not draw upon each other; but the parties
in the interior, who had purchased produce from the merchants,
remitted to the merchants bills on London bankers, or bills
on various parties in London, or bills upon anybody. The
announcement of the Bank of England caused a reduction
of the maturity terms of bills drawn against sales of
foreign products, frequently extending to over three
months" (pp. 26, 27).
The period of prosperity in England from 1844 to 1847, was, as described above, connected with the first great railway swindle. The above-named report makes the following reference to the effect of this swindle on business in general:
In April 1847 "almost all mercantile houses had begun
to starve their business more or less ... by taking part of
their commercial capital for railways" (p.42). "Loans
were made on railway shares at a high rate of interest, say,
8%, by private individuals, by bankers and by fire-offices"
(p. 66). "Loans to so great an extent by commercial
houses to railways induced them to lean too much upon banks
by the discount of paper, whereby to carry on their commercial
operations" (p. 67). (Question:) "Should you say that the
railway calls had had a great effect in producing the
pressure which there was" (on the money-market) "in April
and October" (1847)? — (Answer:) "I should say that they
had had hardly any effect at all in producing the pressure
in April; I should imagine that up to April, and up, perhaps,
to the summer, they had increased the power of bankers in some
respects rather than diminished it; for the expenditure had
not been nearly so rapid as the calls; the consequence
was, that most of the banks had rather a large amount of
railway money in their hands in the beginning of the year."
(This is corroborated in numerous statements made by bankers in C. D. 1848-57.)
"In the summer that melted gradually away, and on the
31st of December it was materially less. One cause ... of the
pressure in October was the gradual diminution of the
railway money in the bankers' hands; between the 22nd of
April and the 31st of December the railway balances in our
hands were reduced one- third; and the railway calls have also
had this effect throughout the Kingdom; they have been
gradually draining the deposits of bankers" (pp. 43, 44).
Samuel Gurney (head of the ill-famed firm of Overend, Gurney and Co.) similarly says:
"During the year 1846 ... there had been a considerable demand
for capital, for the establishment of rail-ways ... but it did not
increase the value of money.... There was a condensation of
small sums into large ma**es, and those large ma**es were
in our market; so that, upon the whole, the effect was to throw
more money into the money-market of the City than to take it
out" [p. 159].
A. Hodgson, Director of the Liverpool Joint-Stock Bank, shows how much bills of exchange may constitute a reserve for bankers:
"It has been our habit to keep at least nine-tenths of all
our deposits, and all money we have of other persons,
in our bill case, in bills that are falling due from day
to day ... so much so, that during the time of the run, the
bills falling due were almost equal to the amount of the
ran upon us day by day" (p. 53).
Speculative bills.
"5092. Who were those bills (against sold cotton)
generally accepted by?" — (R. Gardner, the cotton
manufacturer repeatedly mentioned in this work:) "Produce
brokers: a person buys cotton, and places it in the hands of
a broker, and draws upon that broker, and gets the bills
discounted." — "5094. And they are taken to the banks at
Liverpool, and discounted? — Yes, and in other parts besides....
I believe if it had not been for the accommodation thus
granted, and principally by the Liverpool banks, cotton
would never have been so high last year as it was by 1½ d.
or 2d. a pound." — "600. You have stated that a vast amount
of bills were put in circulation, drawn by speculators upon
cotton brokers in Liverpool; does that system extend to your
advance on acceptances upon colonial and foreign produce
as well as on cotton?" (A. Hodgson, a Liverpool banker:)
"It refers to all kinds of colonial produce, but to
cotton most especially." — "601. Do you, as a banker,
disencourage as far as you can that description of paper?
— We do not; we consider it a very legitimate description of
, when kept in moderation. This description of paper is
frequently renewed."
Swindling in the East Indian and Chinese Market, 1847. — Charles Turner (head of one of the leading East Indian houses in Liverpool):
"We are all aware of the events which have taken place as
regards the Mauritius trade, and other trades of that kind.
The brokers have been in the habit ... not only of advancing
upon goods after their arrival to meet the bills drawn against
those goods, which is perfectly legitimate, and upon the
bills of lading ... but ... they have advanced upon produce
before it was shipped, and in some cases before it was
manufactured. Now, to speak of my own individual instance:
I have bought bills in Calcutta to the extent of six or seven
thousand pounds in one particular instance; the proceeds of
the bills went down to the Mauritius, to help in the
growth of sugar; those bills came to England, and above half
of them were protested; for when the shipments of sugar came
forward, instead of being held to pay those bills, it had
been mortgaged to third parties ... before it was shipped,
in fact almost before it was boiled" (p.78). "Now
manufacturers are insisting upon cash but it does not amount
to much, because if a buyer has any credit in London, he
can draw upon the house, and get the bill discounted; he
goes to London, where discounts now are cheap; he gets
the bill discounted, and pays cash to the manufacturer....
It takes twelve months, at least, for the shipper of goods
to get his return from India ... a man with ten or fifteen
thousand pounds would go into the Indian trade; he would
open a credit with a house in London, to a considerable
extent, giving that house one per cent; he, drawing upon
the house in London, on the understanding that the
proceeds of the goods that go out are to be returned to the
house in London, but it being perfectly understood by
both parties that the man in London is to be kept out of
a cash advance; that is to say, in other words, the bills are
to be renewed till the proceeds come home. The bills were
discounted at Liverpool, Manchester ... or in London
... many of them lie in the Scotch banks" (p. 79). — "786.
There is one house which failed in London the other day,
and in examining their affairs, a transaction of this sort
was proved to have taken place; there is a house of business
at Manchester, and another at Calcutta; they opened a
credit account with a house in London to the extent of
£200,000; that is to say, the friends of this house in
Manchester, who consigned goods to the East India House from
Glasgow and from Manchester, had the power of drawing upon
the house in London to the extent of £200,000; at the same
time, there was an understanding that the corresponding
house in Calcutta were to draw upon the London house to
the extent of £200,000; with the proceeds of those bills
sold in Calcutta, they were to buy other bills, and remit them
to the house in London, to take up the first bills drawn from
Glasgow... There would have been £600,000 of bills created
upon that transaction." — "971. At present, if a house in
Calcutta purchase a cargo" (for England), "and give their
own bills upon their correspondent in London in payment, and
they send the bills of lading home to this country, those
bills of lading ... immediately become available to them
in Lombard Street for advances, and they have eight months'
use of the money before their correspondents are called
upon to pay."
IV. In 1848 a secret committee of the House of Lords investigated the causes of the 1847 crisis. The evidence given to the committee was not published, however, until 1857 (Minutes of Evidence, taken before the Secret Committee of the H. of L. appointed to inquire into the Causes of Distress, etc., 1857; quoted as C.D. 1848/57). Here Mr. Lister, Director of the Union Bank of Liverpool, testified, among other things, to the following:
"2444. In the spring of 1844 there was an undue
extension of credit... because a man transferred property
from business into railways and was still anxious to
carry on the same extent of business. He probably
first thought that he could sell the railway shares at a
profit and replace the money in his business. Perhaps
he found that could not be done, and he then got credit
in his business where formerly he paid in cash. There was
an extension of credit from that circumstance."
"2500. Were those bills ... upon which the banks had sustained a loss by holding them, principally bills upon corn or bills upon cotton?"e; — "They were bills upon all kinds of produce, corn and cotton and sugar, all foreign produce of all descriptions. There was scarcely any thing perhaps with the exception of oil, that did not go down." — "2506. A broker who accepts a bill will not accept it without a good margin as to the value."
"2512. There are two kinds of bills drawn against produce; the first is the original bill drawn abroad upon the merchant, who imports it.... The bills which are drawn against produce frequently fall due before the produce arrives. The merchant, therefore, when it arrives, if he has not sufficient capital, has to pledge that produce with the broker till he has time to sell that produce. Then anew species of bill is immediately drawn by the merchant in Liverpool upon the broker, on the security of that produce.... Then it is the business of the banker to ascertain from the broker whether he has the produce, and to what extent he has advanced upon it. It is his business to see that the broker has property to protect himself if he makes a loss."
"2516. We also receive bills from abroad.... A man buys a bill abroad on England, and sends it to a house in England; we cannot tell whether that bill is drawn prudently or imprudently, whether it is drawn for produce or for wind."
"2533. You said that almost every kind of foreign produce was sold at a great loss. Do you think that that was in consequence of undue speculation in that produce? — It arose from a very large import, and there not being an equal consumption to take it off. It appears that consumption fell off a great deal." — "2534. In October produce was almost unsaleable."
How a general sauve qui peut develops at the height of a crisis is revealed in the same report by a first-rate expert, the esteemed crafty Quaker, Samuel Gurney, of Overend, Gurney and Co.:
"1262 ... When a panic exists a man does not ask himself
what he can get for his bank-notes, or whether he shall
lose one or two per cent by selling his exchequer bills,
or three per cent. If he is under the influence of alarm he
does not care for the profit or loss, but makes himself
safe and allows the rest of the world to do as they please."
V. Concerning the mutual satiation of the two markets Mr. Alexander, a merchant in the East India trade, testifies before the Committee of the, Lower House on the Bank Act of 1857 (quoted as B.C. 1857):
"4330. At the present moment, if I lay out 6s. in Manchester,
I get 5s. back in India; if I lay out 6s. in India, I get 5s.
back in London."
So that the Indian market is, therefore, drugged by England, and the English by India. This was, indeed, the case in the summer of 1857, barely ten years after the bitter experience of 1847!